Features

A beginner’s guide to Adam Smith, part II

Ahead of his talk on Adam Smith at the Edinburgh Fringe Festival, Dominic Frisby looks at some of the great economist's bright ideas.

190813-Smith-634

Adam Smith had many a bright idea

Following on from last week's missive, in which we looked at the life of the great Scottish philosopher, Adam Smith, today I'm going to outline some of his main ideas.

By the end you'll know everything you need to know about Adam Smith.

Almost.

Smith's most famous work An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations is some 950 pages long, while his Theory of Moral Sentiments is another 370-odd pages, so I am inevitably going to gloss over some things.

But, all the same, here we go...

Adam Smith's revolutionary ideas on trade

He argued that instead you should measure a nation's wealth by the value of everything it produces what we would today call GDP (gross domestic product).

It seems obvious today, but it was innovative stuff at the time.

Both sides benefit from trade, he argued, not just the seller. The seller gets your money, but you get his product. Thus restrictions on trade inevitably make both sides poorer.

He argued that both individuals and nations should do what they are good at and trade that. Specialisation boosts productivity. There is no point each of us making our own needles, when we can buy needles from somebody else who makes much better needles than we do and much more cheaply.

Nor is there any point in the people of Scotland making wine, when the French do it so well and so much more cheaply than the Scots ever could. It is better to buy theirs and focus on something else. Nor does it make any sense for governments to try and protect Scottish wine makers "Would it be a reasonable law to prohibit the importation of all foreign wines, merely to encourage the making of claret and burgundy in Scotland?" he asked.

He was a great champion of free markets. Markets are inherently efficient, he thought. If there is a shortage of something, its price will rise and producers will make more of that thing as a result. If there is too much of something, its price will fall, so will profits and producers will thus direct their efforts elsewhere.

It all happens automatically, and legislators think too much of themselves when they think their interventions direct production better than the market.

"He [the legislator] seems to imagine that he can arrange the different members of a great society with as much ease as the hand arranges the different pieces upon a chess-board. He does not consider that in the great chess-board of human society, every single piece has a principle of motion of its own, altogether different from that which the legislature might choose to impress upon it."

In other words, he was no fan of what we would today call central planning. When legislators do intervene, be it by tariff, subsidy or any other form of protection, it is the poor who end up suffering the most, because they end up paying higher prices.

The ideas of Smith have been used to champion the cause of anarchists and anarcho-capitalists (who oppose any form of government at all), but Smith did believe that government was necessary.

Its functions should be to maintain defence, to keep order, build infrastructure and promote education. It should keep the markets open and free, and not act in ways that distort them.

The power of the invisible hand

Despite self-interest, individuals also self-regulate. Prudence moderates excess. Empathy tempers the harm we might do others. An innate sense of morality and justice means we instinctively approve and reward acts that benefit society, but disapprove and punish acts that harm it.

Freedom and self-interest do not, therefore, produce chaos, but order and concord. It is as if we are guided by an "invisible hand". Harmony and prosperity grow, organically, as a result of human nature. By following our instincts, we end up, unintentionally, promoting the betterment of mankind.

"Every individual," he said, "neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it... He intends only his own security; and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention."

Laws and regulations may aim at the same results, but they will never be as consistent or effective as human nature. You cannot force people do good. We do not punish people to force them to do good only for acts of harm.

But they will do good anyway.

"The natural effort of every individual to better his own condition is so powerful, that it is alone, and without any assistance, not only capable of carrying on the society to wealth and prosperity, but of surmounting a hundred impertinent obstructions with which the folly of human laws too often encumbers its operations."

He was a great believer in human nature.

There are probably a hundred Adam Smith ideas that have not made it into this piece for a reasons of space not least his ideas about taxation, which I will cover another time. But you now know enough about Smith to hold court at dinner parties!

And if you want to learn more, and you're up in Edinburgh for the Festival, come to Panmure House, where he lived for the last 12 years of his life, and where he completed Wealth of Nations.

I'm giving a lecture about the history of the Fringe, and how it proved the realisation everything Smith argued for that's Adam Smith: Father of the Fringe.

Or you can discuss the big issues of the day with Merryn, me and guests from the world of politics, economics and finance. That's The Butcher, The Brewer, The Baker and the Commentator. I host from 7-16 August, Merryn hosts 17-25 August.

Recommended

The US Federal Reserve is about to rein in its money-printing – what does that mean for markets?
US Economy

The US Federal Reserve is about to rein in its money-printing – what does that mean for markets?

America’s central bank is talking surprisingly tough about tightening monetary policy. And it’s not the only one. John Stepek looks at what it all mea…
23 Sep 2021
I wish I knew what contagion was, but I’m too embarrassed to ask
Too embarrassed to ask

I wish I knew what contagion was, but I’m too embarrassed to ask

Most of us probably know what “contagion” is in a biological sense. But it also crops up in financial markets. Here's what it means.
21 Sep 2021
Why is the UK short of CO2 and what does it mean for you?
UK Economy

Why is the UK short of CO2 and what does it mean for you?

The UK is experiencing a carbon dioxide shortage that could lead to empty shelves in supermarkets. Saloni Sardana explains what’s going on and how it …
21 Sep 2021
How high energy prices are driving up food prices too
Soft commodities

How high energy prices are driving up food prices too

High energy prices aren’t just affecting our heating bills, they’re making food more expensive, too. Saloni Sardana explains what’s going on.
21 Sep 2021

Most Popular

The times may be changing, but don’t change how you invest
Small cap stocks

The times may be changing, but don’t change how you invest

We are living in strange times. But the basics of investing remain the same: buy fairly-priced stocks that can provide an income. And there are few be…
13 Sep 2021
Two shipping funds to buy for steady income
Investment trusts

Two shipping funds to buy for steady income

Returns from owning ships are volatile, but these two investment trusts are trying to make the sector less risky.
7 Sep 2021
Should investors be worried about stagflation?
US Economy

Should investors be worried about stagflation?

The latest US employment data has raised the ugly spectre of “stagflation” – weak growth and high inflation. John Stepek looks at what’s going on and …
6 Sep 2021