Features

Last word: Why healthcare will become a dirty word

Like unemployment benefits, healthcare will raise the cost of employing workers, claims Amity Shlaes.

Time was when you could rely on taxes to be the topic in the US come mid-April. No longer. This year it's jobs, jobs, jobs. In Washington, Democrats want to extend expiring unemployment insurance. They see their plan as action in the spirit of Franklin Roosevelt, who put forward so many programmes for the worker with his New Deal. Republicans are muttering about what the benefits do to individual initiative. But they are also going along with the plan to extend jobless payments.

The emphasis on extension sounds humane and necessary. Hundreds of thousands of families are losing benefits. Yet that emphasis is counterproductive, because it overlooks the problem that is making it hard for the jobless to get work in the first place. Part of the problem is the relationship between the cost of hiring for employers and the cost of being unemployed for workers. By making hiring expensive through mandates such as health care, the administration is discouraging hiring. By extending benefits for the jobless, the same government is making unemployment less painful cheaper for workers. The combination sustains unemployment at higher levels, not lower.

One economist illuminating this dynamic is Casey Mulligan at the University of Chicago. Mulligan points out that many industries aside from manufacturing are now recovering. But many companies are finding ways to do so with fewer workers. This isn't a general recession any longer. It is becoming a jobs recession where the incentives for employer and employee are out of whack.

Mulligan also notes that there is specific evidence of the counterproductive force of making unemployment less expensive. Two scholars, Stepan Jurajda and Frederick Tannery, looked at Pittsburgh in the first half of the 1980s, a period when the nation had two temporary increases in unemployment benefits. They determined that one third of those claiming unemployment found work within weeks of the expiration of their benefits, but not before. Apply that Pittsburgh experience to today, when insurance is also running out, and what it tells you is that jobs will come back faster if Washington doesn't extend insurance benefits.

The Pittsburgh data is merely a tiny part of a large body of evidence. In policy discussions we make a big deal about the differences in payments to the unemployed, treating 'relief' as different from 'welfare' and 'welfare' as different from 'unemployment insurance'. But they all function the same way: they damp down the incentive to find a job.

The ultimate evidence here is from the 1920s, when the Labour Party came to power in Britain for the first time. Labour passed laws that gave unions power to demand higher wages, and to create unemployment benefits. The result was that employment became more expensive for companies. Unemployment, meanwhile, became relatively less expensive to workers because the workers now received relief payments. As scholars Daniel K. Benjamin and Levis Kochin pointed out in the Journal of Political Economy paper as far back as 1979, the moment was one in which, "unemployment benefits were on a more generous scale relative to wages than ever before or since". The result was the mother of all jobless recoveries. For almost two decades, from 1921 to 1938, UK unemployment averaged 14%, and never got below 9.5%. For two decades Britons talked of the tragedy of 'idleness' and the 'dole'.

One New Deal politician who grasped at least part of what was happening in Britain was that hero of today's Democrats, Roosevelt. Roosevelt understood that relief payments in the UK weren't necessarily helping workers find employment. He appalled his progressive colleagues by disparaging the dole whenever he could. Rather than pay the unemployed, Roosevelt preferred creating jobs through the public sector. Still, Roosevelt and his colleagues replicated other British errors. FDR signed laws that put upward pressure on wages, the most dramatic example of these being the 1935 Wagner Act. This in turn led to real increases in wages, leading to slower hiring.

More recently, the US repeated the pattern in the Aid to Families With Dependent Children programme, which made life worse for those families. They never got work. 'Welfare,' the word we used for the programme, likewise became stigmatised. President Bill Clinton signed the law that abolished the programme, sending a signal that work is better for the country and individual than the dole, relief, or insurance.

US politicians now are reversing that progress, perhaps without being aware of what they're doing. Eventually, they will understand. And eventually those phrases we utter now 'insurance extension', 'mandatory healthcare at the workplace' will also be dropped from the language in shame. But, of course, by then the damage will have been done.

This article was first published on Bloomberg

Recommended

How long can the good times roll?
Economy

How long can the good times roll?

Despite all the doom and gloom that has dominated our headlines for most of 2019, Britain and most of the rest of the developing world is currently en…
19 Dec 2019
The charts that matter: China’s recovery bolsters the yuan
Global Economy

The charts that matter: China’s recovery bolsters the yuan

China's strengthening currency is a sign of confidence in the country's economic recovery. John Stepek looks at the yuan chart, and all of the others …
19 Sep 2020
A “new deal” needn’t be green
UK Economy

A “new deal” needn’t be green

Britain is seeking measures to revive its Covid-ravaged economy. It should choose from a broader palette than just “green”, says Matthew Lynn.
13 Sep 2020
Covid: were the lockdowns worth it?
UK Economy

Covid: were the lockdowns worth it?

Governments around the world followed the authoritarian example of China in dealing with the emergence of Covid-19. Was that a wise choice?
12 Sep 2020

Most Popular

Will a second wave of Covid lead to another stockmarket crash?
Stockmarkets

Will a second wave of Covid lead to another stockmarket crash?

Can we expect to see another lockdown like in March, and what will that mean for your money? John Stepek explains.
18 Sep 2020
Here’s why you really should own at least some bitcoin
Bitcoin

Here’s why you really should own at least some bitcoin

While bitcoin is having a quiet year – at least in relative terms – its potential to become the default cash system for the internet is undiminished, …
16 Sep 2020
James Ferguson: How bad data is driving fear of a second wave of Covid-19
UK Economy

James Ferguson: How bad data is driving fear of a second wave of Covid-19

Merryn and John talk to MoneyWeek regular James Ferguson about the rise in infections in coronavirus and what the data is really telling us.
17 Sep 2020